Consumer adaptation

The FIRE 4% Rule

Mr. Money Mustache blog post on the 4% rule.

A major goal for many in the FIRE (Financial Independence Retire Early) movement is, of course to retire early. They want to build up enough savings and investments so that they can eventually live off the returns of these investments. But how do you know you will have enough money to retire?

This question, in general, requires knowing both about a persons preferences and budget. How much money do you need to live a comfortable life? And then how much do you need accumulated investments to maintain that lifestyle?

Mr. Money Mustache has a simple rule, which he calls the 4% rule. This says that should be able to live off 4% of your total investment wealth. So if you have 1 million euros, you can use 40,000 Euro per year. If you have a preference for more spending, you will need to acquire more savings before you retire.

The logic of the 4% rule an assumption based on historical experience that in the long run you can make 6% returns by investing in a broad index of the stock market (by buying index funds, for example). Then you assume that on average 2% of this will disappear in inflation per year, and then you have 4% real return. If these assumptions hold, then the original principle you have saved up will never be used, just the return on the principle.

As it happens, this 4% rule is also used in slightly different context. The Norwegian state stashes away most of the income it receives from petroleum extraction in an investment fund. The idea was that this fund should benefit not just current citizens of Norway, but also future citizens as well. In order to maintain the principle of the fund, the Government has had a stable policy of only extracting 4% of the funds wealth into the government budgets. This was eventually lowered to 3%, which was seen as a more realistic expectation for future real returns on the fund.

What does this have to do with microeconomics? Deciding when we have accumulated enough wealth to retire requires that we have some idea of both our preferences and our budget. In the previous lessons we have discussed indifference curves, but how do we decide which indifference curve we should be on and where on that indifference curve we should be. That is, what combination of goods do we value? We will try to build a model to help us think about exactly this question in this lesson.

Decisions and consumption

Decisions and consumption 2

Conditions for optimal consumption

    Conditions for optimal consumption

  1. The budget condition: An optimal combination of goods must lie on the budget curve. If a combination lies above the budget line then you can't afford it. If a combination lies below the budget line, then you can increase your utility by buying more of both.
  2. The tangeant condition: The slope of the indifference curve (MRS) is equal to the slope of the budget curve. We can interpret this as the relative prices being in line with your own relative preferences. Say for example that it cost twice as much to buy an apple as a banana, but you prefer them equally (MRS is one). Then you could buy one less apple and instead two more bananas and end up better off.

When prices change...

Marginal willingnesss-to-pay

Demand, marginal willingness-to-pay and consumer surplus

Quiz

Problems

    Assume we have the following Cobb-Douglas utility function:

    $$U(x_a, x_b) = 2*x_a^{0,5}x_b^{0,5}$$

    for consumption of apples and bananas

    The price of bananas (\(p_b\)) is 4 euro per banana.

    The price of apples (\(p_a\)) is 5 euro per apple.

    We have an income of m=100

  1. What is the marginal rate of substitution? (This requires some calculus.)

    We start by deriving the utility function relative to \(x_a\) and \(x_b\) - these derivative represent how much our utility changes when we increase our consumption of apples or bananas (marginal utility):

    $$U_a = \frac{\partial U}{\partial x_a} = x_a^{-0,5}x_b^{0,5} = (\frac{x_b}{x_a})^{0,5}$$ $$U_e = \frac{\partial U}{\partial x_b} = x_a^{0,5}x_b^{-0,5} = (\frac{x_a}{x_b})^{0,5}$$

    We said that the MRS is how much we are willing to give up of the one good to get more of the other good. This we can get by dividing the marginal utility of an apple with the marginal utility of a banana:

    $$MRS = \frac{U_a}{U_e} = \frac{(x_b/x_a)^{0,5}}{(x_a/x_b)^{0,5}} = (\frac{x_b}{x_a})^{0,5}(\frac{x_b}{x_a})^{0,5} = \frac{x_b}{x_a}$$
  2. Write the two conditions needed for an optimu.?

    First we need the tangeant condition (that the slopes of the indifference curve and budget line are the same.)

    $$MRS = \frac{p_a}{p_b} => \frac{x_b}{x_a} = \frac{p_a}{p_b}$$

    Then we need that the budget condition (that our optimal point is on the budget line.)

    $$p_a x_a + p_b x_b = m$$
  3. Find the optimal combination of apples and bananas.

    With our two conditions, we have two equations and two unknowns: \(x_a\) and \(x_b\). We can then find our optimal value (which we denote with a *):

    $$x_a^* = \frac{m}{2p_a} = \frac{100}{2*5} = 10$$ $$x_b^* = \frac{m}{2p_b} = \frac{100}{2*4} = 12,5$$

    (We assume it is possible to buy a half-banana!)

  4. Calculate out the total utility when you have purchased the optimal amount of bananas and apples. Can you provide some interpretation to this number?

    We simply input the values we calculated for optimal bananas and apples into our

    $$U=2*x_a^{0,5}*x_b^{0,5} = 2*\sqrt(10)*\sqrt(12,5) \approx 21,9$$

    Interpreting a utility is in itself meaningless. A utility usually only has meaning when doing a comparison - different combinations of apples and oranges for example.

  5. Let's say that from your current (optimal) consumption, you decide you want to buy 5 more bananas. How many apples do you need to give up in order to afford this? How has our utility changed?

    Each apple costs 4 euros, so then we need 20 euros more. We get this by buying 4 fewer apples (5 euros more). That means we now have 17,5 bananas and 6 apples

    Putting this in our utility function:

    $$U=2*\sqrt(6)*\sqrt(17,5) \approx 20,5$$

    Our utility goes down - a bad deal!

  6. If the price of apples increased, how would this effect the optimal number of bananas to buy?

    Looking at our formula for optimal number of bananas:

    $$x_b^* = \frac{m}{2p_b}$$

    In this particular function, the price of apples does not enter into our decision.

  7. Can you write demand for apples and bananas as a function of prices, \(p_b\), and \(p_a\) and income, \(m\).

    We have already done this (see 3)

    We obtained:

    $$x_a^* = \frac{m}{2p_a} $$ $$x_b^* = \frac{m}{2p_b} $$

    The formulas for optimal amounts of apples and bananas can be interpreted as the demand curves for those goods.